NETFUTURE Technology and Human Responsibility -------------------------------------------------------------------------- Issue #106 A Publication of The Nature Institute May 9, 2000 -------------------------------------------------------------------------- Editor: Stephen L. Talbott (stevet@netfuture.org) On the Web: http://www.netfuture.org/ You may redistribute this newsletter for noncommercial purposes. NetFuture is a reader-supported publication. CONTENTS --------- Editor's Note Quotes and Provocations Laughing Our Way to the Global Village Greed Is Greed Is Greed ... Is Good? The World Trade Organization: Economics as Technology (Stephen L. Talbott) There is no such thing as a commodity Who Owns Microsoft's Profits? (Stephen L. Talbott) Capitalism is about assigning value where value is due DEPARTMENTS Announcements and Resources The Child and the Machine User-specified Tools for Online Collaboration About this newsletter ========================================================================== EDITOR'S NOTE An issue devoted to economics and commerce -- and, in particular, various ramifications of this puzzle: If freeing the distributed power of diverse, individual initiative is crucial to capitalism, why is it that the particular nature of the individual's action, healthy or unhealthy, greedy or caring, isn't thought to matter much? Or, if it does matter, why aren't more of capitalism's defenders, for the sake of their own hopes, out there vigorously promoting responsible individual action and combatting irresponsible action? The answer turns out to have a lot to do with the way our minds have been taken over by technological habits of thinking. I guarantee you I'll get some vitriolic responses on this one. (Virginia Postrel, are you there?) SLT Goto table of contents ========================================================================== QUOTES AND PROVOCATIONS Laughing Our Way to the Global Village -------------------------------------- This came through via NewsScan Daily (April 18): Remember DotTV? The Idealab-sponsored company cut a deal with the Pacific Island nation of Tuvalu to sell Internet domain names using its ".tv" suffix. DotTV began taking registrations last week, and has already raked in half a million dollars in revenue and changed its business plan to auction off names to the highest bidder rather than sell them for a fixed price. "We'd be disappointed if we don't see names going in excess of a million dollars in the next year," says DotTV CEO Lou Kerner. So what's next? Moldova is cashing in communism for e-capitalism, having made a pact with a Florida firm allowing it to register medical sites with a ".md" suffix, and South Pacific's Niue has signed on with .NU Domain Ltd. to sell ".nu" names. And why is ".nu" in demand, you might ask? In addition to representing "new," "nu" is also French for "naked." (Investor's Business Daily 18 Apr 2000) Sovereign nations selling their names for a little bit of that dot-com wealth -- I have to admit, it almost gives me hope. Perhaps the forces of a debauched commercial globalization will finally exhaust themselves -- not in a great and disastrous apocalypse, but in a laugh-until-you-expire comic convulsion. Greed Is Greed Is Greed ... Is Good? ------------------------------------ Denise Caruso's "Digital Commerce" column in the March 27 New York Times was headlined, "Technology has transformed the economy and made some people a lot of money, but is that all there is?" In the column she mentions venture capitalist John Doerr, who famously remarked that the digital technology boom has yielded the greatest legal creation of wealth in history. But, says Caruso, there are changes in the air: Venture investors, the rocket fuel of the Internet economy, have started to question the path that so many Internet companies have taken -- despite the tremendous profit they make from the present state of affairs. In fact, at a recent conference, Mr. Doerr apologized to the assembled crowd for his "legal creation of wealth" remark, saying that he never expected everyone to focus on the money, to the exclusion of creating substantial businesses. Personally, however, I don't see much hope for real change until one of the most entrenched dogmas of our day has been pried loose from the nation's psyche. I mean the libel against capitalism that says it makes a virtue out of greed. You encounter the libel everywhere -- even in pleas for a return to sanity. Here's how it comes out when Caruso interviews long-time Silicon Valley player, Randy Komisar: "We're moving toward the toxic extreme of capitalism," Mr. Komisar said in an interview last week. Capitalism works better than any other market structure that has been devised, he added, because it harnesses man's "absolute base instincts -- greed and aggression." But a focus on money, to the exclusion of substance and human relationships, he said, will ultimately fail, perhaps spectacularly. It's nice to hear Komisar calling for at least some attention to substance and human relationships. And it's nice that he worries about the "toxic extreme of capitalism". But how can we escape that extreme without recognizing and countering the sources of toxicity? Greed is, inescapably, toxic. There is no special capitalist magic when it comes to greed. We are imperfect creatures, and it's true that our families often can survive our imperfections, as can our governing institutions, our civic organizations, our churches -- and, yes, our businesses. "Can survive", I say -- but this requires that what Komisar refers to as our "absolute base instincts" be hedged around by social convention, institutional safeguards, a healthy education, a will toward self-improvement, and so on. It also requires that, when a particular base instinct comes disturbingly to the fore in society, we begin to work on its taming in a more conscious and explicit way. And, for this purpose, saying that we can be as greedy as we wish because the market will make a virtue of our greed hardly qualifies as the right sort of work. The fact is that greed has exactly the same destructive consequences in business as it has elsewhere. Employees and customers and competitors who get walked over by my selfish interest in personal gain are not somehow exempted by the laws of capitalism from suffering the kind of hurt this behavior inflicts in other arenas. Nor are businesses, any more than families and civic organizations, exempt from the stresses caused by such hurt -- stresses that impose huge economic costs. Nor are the end products of a business likely to be healthy for society when those products were conceived by selfishly grasping minds looking only for personal advantage. What blinds so many people to the obvious, I think, is that, in their thinking about capitalism, they remove their gaze from people and living contexts, and look instead at the abstract, numerical functioning of what they imagine to be a huge, economic machine. The parameters of this machine -- quantities such as gross domestic product, standard of living, and unemployment rate -- are convenient to deal with, and their theoretical manipulation offers many intellectual satisfactions. But these parameters are hopelessly inadequate to reality (see following article). And it is easy to forget, in this rather-too-neat world of clean constructs, that the whole point of a figure such as standard of living is, in the end, to help us come to grips with the welfare of human beings -- the same human beings whose lives are made miserable by the greed of their fellows. No, capitalism does not harness greed and turn it into good. What it harnesses is diverse individual choice and initiative, which it weaves, without central planning, into a collective tapestry. This is its great virtue. But the virtue in no way obviates the fact that the tapestry, beautiful or soiled, depends on those individual choices, beautiful or soiled. When the choices are driven more and more by greed, society sickens -- precisely because capitalism grounds society so fundamentally upon the individual's freedom. It may be that there were more restraining forces at work in our society in earlier times, forces just "imposed" upon us (as Adam Smith suggested), setting rough bounds to our behavior. But restraining is not the same as turning evil into good. And these culturally enforced restraining bonds are exactly what today's culture-destroying, out-of-control commerce is so effectively bursting. The devil in us is being let loose. We have no choice but to take up the task that our own history is setting before us: where before we had the luxury of remaining half asleep, now we must, in all moral seriousness, consciously choose what sort of society we will create. You can see signs everywhere that this necessity is dawning on people today. Just look at the frenzy of "we can build a new society" impulses that have engulfed the Net (and also the despair as the same old anything- for-a-buck commercial powers appropriate the Net for their own purposes). What is necessary is to take on the hard work of purging these worthy impulses of their worst contradictions. And the grandest of the contradictions is the belief that we can build a new and better society without taking responsibility for ourselves. To rejoice that capitalism unleashes the creative power of millions of individuals is quite proper; to turn around and sheepishly say, "Now that the individual has been unleashed, it turns out that it doesn't matter much what the hell he does" -- well, then, why all the fuss about the creative potentials of the individual in the first place? Or have we discovered some new sort of creative power with potential for good but not for evil? You tell me: is all this really so hard to see? --------------------- Related articles: ** "Beyond the Dreams of Avarice (Part 2: I'm Stiffing You for the Good of Society" in NF #60. Does the Invisible Hand transmute evil into good? SLT Goto table of contents ========================================================================== THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION: ECONOMICS AS TECHNOLOGY Stephen L. Talbott (stevet@netfuture.org) If you want to grasp what is pathological about the World Trade Organization (WTO), a good place to start is with a remark by Maine forester, Mitch Lansky: We've reached a point in our society where consumers have no idea where things come from, or how they're produced. They just want cheap products. But, unfortunately, when commodities are cheap, what produces the commodities has to be cheap as well. That means, in our case, cheapened forests, cheapened workers, and cheapened communities. (Orion Afield, Fall, 1999) In other words -- and I think this is Lansky's point -- a commodity isn't really just a commodity; it is an inextricable part of its environment and our own way of life. That's the stumbling block -- you might almost say the mountain range -- we need to get past today. Commodities in the narrow sense don't exist, and the mistaken notion that they do is one of the primary errors with which the WTO would infect the world. A commodity, according to the wisdom of the WTO, is a reasonably self- contained, well-defined entity that can be transported from here to there and whose value can be defined wholly in terms of what is transported. Once this value has been set by corporations that are as unrooted as the products they traffic in, woe be unto any nation that tries to understand the product in its wholeness and let the market deal with the full reality of it. What we see here is outmoded atomism with a vengeance. It wrenches the commodity out of the environmental and communal context that alone enables its existence, rather as if we tried to understand and productively use the leaves of trees while denying ourselves any reference to root, trunk, and branch. Friction-free Capitalism Is Context-free Capitalism --------------------------------------------------- The wrench, of course, is quite possible and even legitimate for certain functions of the intellect. What is not legitimate is to forget the artificiality of the exercise. It is physically impossible, after all, merely to buy a potato, as if it had suddenly materialized out of nothing. You also buy a farming practice, a style of rural community, a set of labor practices, a transport, wholesale, and retail system, and an altered ecological balance. But we are not allowed, in the WTO's world, to assess and take responsibility for the full range of consequences of our own actions as consumers. This disastrous mandate for moral detachment and irresponsibility is hardly surprising; it is the playing out of the original economic premise that capitalism includes a kind of alchemy, transmuting greed into social good. How do you reinstate a concern for qualities and values once you have turned a willfully blind eye toward avarice? The upshot of all this is that when a nation tries to recognize the full reality of an imported product, restoring it to its context and seeking to account for the true costs of its production and consumption, then the offended corporations can use the WTO to cry "foul" and force that nation to return to one-dimensional economic falsehoods. This is how it happened that the U.S. could use the WTO to overturn a European ban on hormone-treated meat. It is also how it happened that the WTO disallowed a U.S. environmental regulation stipulating that imported shrimp must be harvested without causing undue danger to sea turtles. And it is how the WTO has positioned itself to overrule all efforts to stengthen local economies based on knowledge of the peculiar social and environmental requirements of a particular community. The WTO policy of enforced decontextualization reflects a pathology of thinking. It is a pathology that has led legions of economists to spend thousands of man-years erecting sophisticated theoretical edifices upon a foundation of make-believe concepts like "commodity" -- this despite the few open-eyed economists such as Herman Daly who occasionally point out the absurdity of such an approach. Perhaps the purest expression of the pathology -- as of so many unbalanced tendencies today -- is found in the online world. Numerous premature declarations have proclaimed the Internet to be the ideal world the WTO is striving for. The whole idea behind the celebration of the supposedly friction-free capitalism delivered by e-commerce is that we're finally creating the non-communities of non-peoples the economists have yearned for as a fulfillment of their abstract theorizing. On the Net we are supposed to have commodities as the perfect, friction-free atoms moving to and fro with delicious efficiency -- something they can do precisely because they drag nothing of their friction-inducing contexts with them. On this view, a commodity put up for sale at any single node in the world can compete on exactly equal terms with a commodity offered at any other node, because they are presumed to be exactly equivalent. Their contexts -- real people living in real communities; environments that can be qualitatively enhanced or degraded -- fall out of the picture on the Net with an ease that must make the entrepreneurial titans behind the WTO drool in anticipation. Basing Policy on Falsehood -------------------------- The false notions represented by "commodity" and "friction-free capitalism" are the easy way out for theorists. Our several hundred years' experience with machines, along with our disregard of organisms, has taught us to think in the simplified and manageable terms of stasis, discrete entities, and precisely definable, formal relations between the separable parts of things -- what could be called "technological thought". (This thought, incidentally, is even more extreme -- not overcome -- in the work of complexity theorists. But that's another article.) The result of this habit -- and its near-perfection in the field of economics -- is that (in Bill McKibben's words) abstractions like the economy have become more real to people than the physical world in which we live. It's easier for them to visualize dangers to the economy than it is for them to visualize dangers to the planet. ("Warning Skies: The Deeper Aspects of Climate Change", Lapis #10) It's fine for the economist to idealize and decontextualize his working concepts. What is not so fine is to turn around and impose these one- dimensional concepts, which now become powerful distorting factors, upon real-world contexts. A decontextualized concept is always false to the context from which it came, pretty much by definition. This falseness is given power over us when, in the world of actual exchange, we treat commodities as if they really were things we could buy in isolation from everything that is in fact inseparable from them. And the same falseness is institutionalized when economists armed with one-dimensional concepts advise governments, corporations, and individuals how to behave within the complex matrix of society and the natural world. Economists do acknowledge the problems of context in a backhanded sort of way when they refer to "externalities" -- costs (or benefits) not reflected in the price of something. But neither the holistic movement of thought through which we recognize externalities, nor the behavior motivated by such imaginative insight, is given adequate place within the economist's world. It is positively scorned in the corporation-driven world of the WTO. A Market in Choices vs. a Market Mechanism ------------------------------------------ To truly address any one problem in its social and humane dimensions is to discover that it is no longer a single, narrowly conceived, precisely defined problem. You have to visualize the whole -- and then, like a painter reconceiving a canvas, imagine how this whole might "go fluid", evolving lawfully into other, slightly different wholes in which everything has changed. This is the imaginative exercise the WTO would like to make illegal. Or, rather, it would make illegal any choice to act upon one's imagination of a better world, because this would be to introduce considerations "alien" to the clean, mathematically precise valuation of particular commodities severed from their own wholes. We must not allow citizens to choose what sort of world they will live in, but instead must hope that a pure calculus of number will automatically create the world of their choice. Given the falseness built into these decontextualized numbers, this hope amounts to a belief in magic -- and our societal commitment to the efficacy of the magic is one of history's most striking cases of mass delusion. It all comes down to this: To say that the market -- the place where we exercise free and individual choice -- has become more important in our day, is also to say that your and my choices have become more important. Why, then, do so many of those preaching the virtues of the market want the WTO to disallow free, individual choice -- and disallow it where it matters most to us? The answer, I think, is that they don't really believe in a free market, that is, a market between free and responsible individuals. What they want is a market mechanism -- something that functions automatically and without the messy complications introduced by individuals responsible for choosing what sort of world they will live in. The Internet and the WTO, as we have them today, fit together remarkably well in delivering a vision of global society as a grand machine. We Must Globalize ----------------- There is, I believe, deep within the WTO's promoters, a sense for this truth: We are entering a global era; it is our future. The world has never seen its like before. We do not have the choice of shutting ourselves up behind rigidly isolationist barriers. We must increasingly discover what it means to be global citizens. I, too, believe this. And I worry that some of those (at times I am numbered among them) who fight against the forces of a destructive globalization are so frozen by fear of the powers they see let loose that they lose sight of the positive mandate. Yet, it is only through our grasp of a positive counter-image that we can combat what is unhealthy. So what does it mean to be a global citizen? Here's one way to begin thinking about it: It is imperative for the indivdidual to retain a certain openness to those around him -- for example, openness to the ideas of others. In fact, his growth as an individual will depend on this openness. But at the same time, mere openness -- passive yielding to every thought that approaches him -- is less a matter of openness than emptiness. It is the end of individuality. If he does not have his own particular character to preserve and develop in dynamic interaction with others -- and if those others, too, are lacking any such character -- then what we're looking at is not so much a society of individuals as a bland collection of nobodies. From where, after all, does a group derive its vitality, from where does it derive all the things worth passing around and sharing, if not from the distinctive achievements of its members? Of course, once you see this, you also see it the other way around: the indivdidual can only thrive to the fullest in a community. What you have here is a polar tension (see NF #84) between the individual and society. And, as with all such polar tensions, each pole exists only by grace of its opposite. Give Us Market Choice --------------------- Let this discussion of individual and group stand as an analogy (actually, it's more than an analogy) to the dynamics of globalization and free trade. The question for those who are gripped by the compelling logic of global free trade is this: "How do you work into this logic its polar opposite principle, so as to prevent this free trade from becoming, finally, an empty exchange of meaningless things? How do you preserve the diversity, the distinctive contributions, the valuable local realities, that alone can make global exchange desirable?" I have written before that the only way to globalize today is to strengthen today's badly weakened local center. If you want ripples to extend farther toward the edges of the lake, the stone you drop in the center must be weightier. But, of course, every place on the globe is a center. The earth consists of nothing else but locales and neighborhoods, so there is, in a very real sense, nothing to do except to localize. Proper globalization can only arise out of this process, as an expression of the healthy locale's need to transcend itself on the way to preserving itself. The more intensely these local centers are cultivated, the more diverse and richly meaningful will be their possible ways of connecting with each other. If this is true, and if cultural diversity entails making room for different, competing sets of values -- including values placed on sea turtles and carcinogenic hormones injected into meats -- then we just can't have the mathematical economist's precious notion of decontextualized commodities moving along frictionless global trajectories. It is vastly more complicated than that. What the globalizer owes us is a full and explicit set of reflections upon this polar relation between globalization and localization. Does he care about local places and diverse cultures? If not, how does a global collection of noplaces become worth striving for? If, on the other hand, he does care, how does this care play into his policy recommendations? "But if we grant what you are asking, we'd have to give up on global free trade altogether! There would only be a chaotic collection of nations, each going its own way." No, no, no. Go back to the earlier analogy. It is the truest individuals who become most universally human and capable of the farthest global reach. Surely the same applies to the relation between local communities and the larger community of mankind. Listen. Don't you believe your own rhetoric? Don't you believe there are enticing benefits to be had from global exchange? Do you doubt that free peoples, exercising their own choices and doing their best to understand all the dimensions of a product -- a product embedded in the real world and not just in the theoretical matrix of economists -- do you doubt that these people will be inclined to make choices to their own advantage, wherever there really is an advantage? If you do doubt it, what business do you have urging capitalist doctrine? We have crossed a threshold, impelled by an unstoppable urge toward universality. But we can embrace this universality only by becoming more truly free, individual, and communally rooted. Don't deny us the kind of wise, deeply contextualized choice through which we can establish ourselves as individuals and at the same time connect to the whole. It is, after all, context alone that produces global, meaningful wholes, as opposed to the mere aggregation and glut of things. --------------------- (There is an alternative vision to the one sponsored by the WTO. It is articulated by Nicanor Perlas in his new book, Shaping Globalization: Civil Society, Cultural Power and Threefolding. I hope to review this book in the near future.) Related articles: ** "Want to Globalize? Then Localize!" in NF #84. ** "Beyond the Dreams of Avarice (Part 3: A Taste for Number Magic)" in NF #68. Reflections on the quantitative side of the technological thought of economics. Goto table of contents ========================================================================== WHO OWNS MICROSOFT'S PROFITS? Stephen L. Talbott (stevet@netfuture.org) Notes concerning Mephistopheles' Anvil: Forging a More Human Future, by John Alexandra (Spring Valley, N.Y.: Rose Harmony Publications, 1996). Hardcover, 349 pages, $24.95. One of the glories of capitalism is its ability to establish reasonable values for things. Somehow, out of the chaos of perhaps millions of separate transactions in the marketplace, the approximately correct value for a good or service declares itself. Or, at least, can declare itself. It requires some wise and subtle adjustment of many institutions -- adjustments learned through long, hard experience -- to make the system work. But it works well enough to provide us with a near-miracle of continual, organic readjustment among the countless claims and counter-claims of producers and consumers. It's cause for worry among those of us inclined toward capitalism when a systematic distortion of values occurs. One such distortion has in fact been occurring for a long time, and it has a lot to do with our ideas of ownership. John Alexandra, executive vice president and chief financial officer of NewCentury Bank in Phoenixville, Pennsylvania, discusses the matter in his book, Mephistopheles' Anvil: Forging a More Human Future. Alexandra spent eleven years at the Wall Street investment firm, J.P. Morgan, where he was a vice president. Interestingly, he was also a teacher for seventeen years, with students ranging from first grade to college. And, beside his MBA in finance, he holds an MA in mathematics and physics. His breadth of life experience shows itself refreshingly in the humane dimensions of his book. How Do You Make a Calculator from Nothing? ------------------------------------------ Alexandra asks who is responsible for the invention of the modern electronic calculator. Certainly the engineers who produced the finished product deserve a lot of credit. But behind them lay a long history of scientific work, including Newton's development of the calculus and Michael Faraday's formulation of the principles of electricity. Without these, there would be no calculator. "Newton's research, done centuries ago, is thus a contributor to the capital-creation that takes place today when a calculator makes an accountant more productive." In these various contributions, we can distinguish between what is more fundamental and long-lasting, and what is less so. For example, the engineers who design a keypad for efficient use definitely contribute to the value of the calculator. But There is a significant economic contrast ... between this research and Newton's. Although the keypad research, which is less fundamental than Newton's, is more likely to yield immediate economic returns, it will also become obsolete more quickly. One of the early weaving machines probably generated greater economic returns in a few years than the application of calculus generated during Newton's whole lifetime. But this specialized machine soon ceased to be productive. The productive application of calculus, by contrast, although it began much later and more slowly, has lasted for centuries. Similarly, Alexandra imagines a student who learns to type at secretarial school. The new skill immediately makes him more productive. But what he learned at secretarial school is perhaps less important than his manual dexterity and habits of care, which he learned in his earliest years. If he failed to develop dexterity as a child, he will not easily overcome the failure as an adult. Typing, on the other hand, can be learned at almost any age. In sum, A typing training increases people's short-term productivity far more than learning calculus. A training in accurate thinking, however, as well as specific mathematical skills, will probably be vastly more economically productive in the long-term than typing skills. Kindergarten teachers, and others around young children, help develop the dexterity fundamental to all later abilities, as well as the foundation for thinking, and basic qualities such as motivation, creativity, patience, care, etc. These people generally contribute far more to long-term productivity than do typing instructors (or engineering professors, for that matter). Fundamental education is productive for an individual's whole lifetime, just as fundamental research can be productive for centuries. What Is Most Human Is Most Productive ------------------------------------- Alexandra makes the crucial point that the most fundamental and long-term gains in productivity stem from the activities that are most universally human -- and these activities tend to be furthest from, rather than closest to, the production process. When Newton was developing calculus, he probably had little idea of, or even interest in, its technological applications. His interest was purely human. He wanted to understand the movements of the heavenly bodies, particularly the planets. Likewise, the kindergarten teacher's principal interest is not the children's future jobs, but to develop to the fullest their latent human potential. So Newton's invention is still creating capital. Why should this part of the capital resulting from the manufacture of calculators belong either to the capitalists or the workers? Alexandra calls this capital "free" because it comes essentially as a gift without strings -- just as Newton, who himself produced no economic commodities, was the beneficiary of gift money. In this way gift capital flows forward through time, accounting for what is most creative and fruitful and unexpected in a culture, because it is not strictly tied (as lending capital properly is) to a particular production process. The capital created today through Newton's research belongs neither to the workers nor the capitalists. Nor can it be given to Newton. It is therefore "free" -- available to support other fundamentally creative and more universally human activities, such as fundamental education and research. The capital generated in the future through these latter activities will then again be free capital. Alexandra illustrates the situation from the life of Ernst Abbe, the son of a poor factory worker. Abbe eventually became owner of the Carl Zeiss optical instrument company in Jena, Germany. He analyzed his own situation, Alexandra points out, clearly and precisely. He reasoned as follows: "My father worked hard, but was poor. I have worked no harder than he, yet I am rich. What has made the difference?" His answer was: "In addition to what my workers have contributed, the success of the factory is due to my education and to the scientific research I have been able to use." So he gave a large portion of his profits to the university in Jena. And, recognizing his workers' contribution, he provided them with unusual benefits. For him, this had nothing to do with giving alms, but was a matter of social insight. He himself lived a relatively simple life. Coerced Giving -------------- Today the flows of free capital are cramped as a result of their passage through inappropriate bureaucracies: Taxation and its associated government spending are the major conduit for free capital-flows in a modern economy. Taxes are, essentially, coerced gift-capital, since the taxpayer has to pay them and receives no direct return, and the revenues support such universally human creative activities as education and research. They force us to do what we cannot or will not do through conscious recognition. Yet, since these coerced gifts are hampered by expensive, bureaucratic procedures, enormous problems and inefficiencies result. The resulting capital-flows are much less effective than those provided directly by people able to recognize those researchers and educators with significant capacities. Insight, which is essential to the fruitful application of capital, is not exactly the government's forte or even its appropriate domain. Government funding of education, for example, helps to right the social injustice of education being available only to the wealthy. Simultaneously, it cramps the educational process itself through the bureaucracy and regulations attached to the funding, which are death to any creative process. This is why, despite our massive spending on education, "nothing remotely resembling a blossoming of culture has taken place". Alexandra, by the way, is not arguing against government in general. He is only questioning the government-imposed redirection of free (gift) capital. This capital should be gifted toward cultural endeavors -- art, science, education -- through the free agency of the individual. The government's responsibilities, on this view, have to do with the sphere of activity where we must all be treated as "equal before the law". Free capital, by contrast, serves the expression of our creative capacities, wherein we are decidedly unequal. It's one thing for government to do its best to guarantee equal access to education (which it should do), but quite another to control and specify the spirit that speaks through this education. (This is the sort of distinction we desperately need to learn to make if we are to overcome simplistic and destructive oppositions such as "free market vs. government".) Stewardship Is Not Ownership ---------------------------- In light of the considerations Alexandra raises, it does not make sense to say that the capitalist owners of a business have a valid claim upon the profits of the business, without limit. Nor is there anything about the spirit of capitalism that requires such an unrealistic claim. In general, our notions of ownership have suffered a kind of rigor mortis that is unseemly under an economic regime celebrating continual change. Unfortunately, however, the discussion of economic alternatives remains so horribly shackled by the ghosts of old battles -- in particular, the battle between capitalism and socialism -- that some capitalists apparently can't bring themselves to believe they really won. And so their knee-jerk reaction to the suggestion that they can't rightly claim as their own all the profits of their businesses is, "You mean you want central planners to run the economy?" What this ignores is that you can alter the rules of capital distribution while leaving the work of distribution -- though not the ground rules -- to the realm of diverse, free, individual choice. It's just that some of those choices now become a matter of stewardship rather than personal ownership. After all, we already have, in the huge nonprofit sector, one kind of limit upon the claim to profits. But where these unowned profits go is not centrally decreed; it is determined by individuals and groups who, in all their unsurveyable variety, act as trustees for the funds (and not always according to healthy rules; there's plenty to work on here). There is a whole world of possibility regarding corporate structure and ownership. Should we claim, against all the usual capitalist hopes for innovation and improvement, that the peculiar set of legal forms we now have -- evolved from the peculiar and sometimes distorted historical experience of one capitalist nation -- are the final, divinely decreed norms for corporations? If we truly believed in the ferment, the experimentation, the continual exploration of alternatives that capitalism is so good at encouraging, we would be working especially hard at devising new corporate forms that reflected more accurately the historical and cultural realities of ownership. For the historical fact of the matter, if not the current legal fact, is that the stockholders do not own all of Microsoft's profits. --------------------- (The discussion cited above is only one small part of Alexandra's valuable book, which offers a wide-ranging characterization of technology's role in contemporary society.) Related articles: ** "Beyond the Dreams of Avarice (Part 1: Is There Life after Communism?)" in NF #57. Goto table of contents ========================================================================== ANNOUNCEMENTS AND RESOURCES The Child and the Machine ------------------------- The Whole Alliance is presenting a one-day (9 am to 1 pm), Los Angeles- area workshop entitled "The Child and the Machine". The workshop will feature Alison Armstrong (co-author of The Child and the Machine), Alan Kay (well known commentator on computers and education), and William Rukeyser (director of Learning in the Real World, www.realworld.org). The event will take place at the Satellite Student Union, Shoshone Room, California State University, Northridge. Cost is $15 per person. The Whole Alliance describes itself as "a bridge-building initiative focused on creating more dynamic and decentralized K-12 educational options. Whole Alliance is part of a global initiative networking social entrepreneurs to reconceive our social architecture and institutions to better profit individuals, families, and communities, protect the biosphere, and take responsibility for the positive evolution of greater social awareness and human consciousness". See www.whole.org for more information. You will find there a list of the other sponsors, including the Alliance for Childhood (see NF #99). User-specified Tools for Online Collaboration --------------------------------------------- NetFuture reader Aldo de Moor has completed a Ph.D. dissertation that some of you may be interested in. Here are a few sentences from the preface: All over the world, forests are disappearing at an alarming rate. I usd to be quite involved in several forest conservation campaigns. However, while working on these issues, it became increasingly clear to me that there are no simple solutions for dealing with this very urgent problem. The only way to address complex issues like this is to involve many people, who represent a wide range of stakeholders, in a continuous dialogue. ....time and again we found out how difficult it is to keep prolonged and intensive computer-enabled collaboration going. People would start to work together enthusiastically, but somehow, results failed to materialize, after which participation would wane quickly. This despite common goals and considerable initial efforts of the participants, and despite the fact that when the same networks of professionals meet physically, collaboration is often successful indeed. While investigating these failures, I found out that the problems encountered are not particular to our network. In fact, similar breakdowns are reported in a wide body of literature on computer supported cooperative work. In working on this problem, de Moor produced "a theory of legitimate user- driven specification, as well as a supporting method and [software] tool. They should enable members of virtual professional communities to use their potential for collaboration to create network information systems that better meet the communal needs". De Moor wrote his thesis at Tilburg University in The Netherlands, and summaries of it in English and Dutch, as well as information for obtaining English copies of the entire thesis, are available at http://infolab.kub.nl/people/ademoor/phd . Goto table of contents ========================================================================== ABOUT THIS NEWSLETTER Copyright 2000 by The Nature Institute. You may redistribute this newsletter for noncommercial purposes. You may also redistribute individual articles in their entirety, provided the NetFuture url and this paragraph are attached. NetFuture is supported by freely given reader contributions, and could not survive without them. For details and special offers, see http://netfuture.org/support.html . Current and past issues of NetFuture are available on the Web: http://netfuture.org/ To subscribe or unsubscribe to NetFuture: http://netfuture.org/subscribe.html. Steve Talbott :: NetFuture #106 :: May 9, 2000 Goto table of contents